Chapter 8
Demand-side participation and response to technological and market changes
8.1
This final chapter considers the response of the regulator, rule-maker
and network businesses to emerging technologies, changes in how consumers use
electricity and concerns about a 'death spiral'. After introducing these issues,
the chapter examines in detail:
-
embedded generation and the potential for local energy trading;
-
whether the connection and pricing of network services is
discriminating against households and businesses involved in their own electricity
production;
-
demand management; and
-
calls for network tariff reform.
Introduction
8.2
As noted in Chapter 2, electricity prices, largely driven by network
costs, have risen significantly while the demand for electricity has declined. This
had led to concern about a death spiral; that is, high prices are causing
demand to decline while also encouraging consumers and businesses to engage in
their own generation activities. Remaining customers would be required to pay an
increasing share of the network costs while network assets become
under-utilised or stranded.
8.3
It is already evident that the ability to generate electricity through
systems such as solar photovoltaic (PV) panels is changing how consumers are
engaging with the electricity network. Emerging and future technologies, such
as more effective battery storage, may change consumer behaviour more
dramatically. This potential has gained some level of recognition at various
levels of government, as evidenced by the following statement included in the
Department of Industry's submission:
Emerging technologies will increase the range of methods for
stakeholders across the sector to manage demand and address network
constraints. This may begin to challenge the traditional concept of
networks services being delivered by monopoly businesses. The Council of
Australian Governments (COAG) Energy Council is looking into the economic
regulatory frameworks to make sure it is well positioned for the future by
'stress‑testing' its ability to efficiently adapt under a range of
possible physical and technical changes.[1]
8.4
The committee received evidence indicating that the energy industry has recognised
the changes underway and that some network companies were considering how to
respond. The chief executive officer of the Energy Supply Association of
Australia (ESAA) noted that the 'energy supply system in Australia has already
begun a rapid transformation to an unknown future, driven by new technologies
and necessity'.[2]
8.5
Mr Alistair Parker, the general manager of asset management at AusNet
Services, also commented that change to its network 'is happening fast [and]...it
is happening now'. He explained that his company was already seeking to 'avoid
investments that may prove to be regrettable in the future'. Mr Parker also
discussed what was considered to be the worst-case scenario, where only half of
the network was needed by 2050. He outlined his company's position on this
potential outcome:
If we only need half our network in 2050, we are going to
make sure we only have half the network left when we get there, if that makes
sense. I do not think for our purposes we are assuming that we can
continue to build and build and then one day it will be only one unfortunate
person in paddock in Bendigo who is paying all our bills. We assume that we
will wind down. We will have active asset management processes that will get us
to the right size at the right time.[3]
8.6
Given the unpredicted decline in demand during previous regulatory
control periods and the possible widespread deployment of disruptive
technologies in the future, the committee was interested in whether modelling
and forecasting of demand had improved. Of particular interest was whether
network businesses and regulatory institutions would be more attuned to future
market developments. Mr Terence Effeney, the chief executive officer of
Energex, advised that his company has 'taken on board the fact that our
previous econometric models did not match this new future'. He added:
...those matters have been reviewed and revised and I am
pleased to say that our model now does appear to be giving us outcomes which
were consistent with the summer which we have just had; whereas previously that
was not the case. But it was not just our model. The reality of it is that
we were using the AEMO models; we were using the AER models. Nobody's models
were picking up some of those changes that were occurring across the last five
years; that is true.[4]
8.7
The remaining sections of this chapter examine some of the key areas of potential
change. The focus of this chapter is to consider the implications of change for
consumers overall, electricity network businesses and the regulatory system.
Decentralised energy
8.8
The traditional model of electricity supply is based on a limited number
of large generators connected to local distribution networks by large
transmission networks. Gradually, there has been a rise in 'embedded
generation', which is also known as distributed generation.[5]
These terms refer to generators embedded in the distribution network, rather
than connected to customers by transmission networks. Smaller embedded
generators include rooftop solar PV units, wind generating units, battery
storage and batteries in electric vehicles that export power to the grid.
Cogeneration and trigeneration are other examples of embedded generators.[6]
8.9
The Australian Energy Market Commission (AEMC) has noted that there are
a range of benefits associated with embedded generation. These include that:
-
consumers who install embedded generation units may have reduced
electricity costs or improved reliability outcomes;
-
embedded generation may 'help reduce the cost of power system
augmentation, helping to reduce the overall cost of supply faced by consumers';
and
-
growth in embedded generation may displace other more
emissions-intensive generation and in doing so help to reduce the overall
emissions related to the National Electricity Market (NEM).[7]
8.10
Embedded generation presents challenges to the existing electricity
networks that were built to cater for centralised generation. This follows the
discussion in Chapter 2 that in response to high prices, consumers would seek to
use embedded generation to move 'off-grid'. If such decisions were widespread,
network companies would have vast, expensive infrastructure that was serving a
declining number of customers. As EnergyAustralia observed, those fewer
customers would be 'left to pay the same quantum of network costs'.[8]
8.11
Some of the evidence taken by the committee suggested a sense of
inevitability about the rise of embedded generation, particularly solar.
A representative of the Electrical Trades Union told the committee:
Coming from far North Queensland, I cannot understand why the
whole of far North Queensland cannot be self-sufficient on renewable
electricity. There is so much opportunity. You have the transmission lines that
run and you have an impact there—it was only a few years ago that there was a
major failure of the transmission network which took out the whole of regional
Queensland because of bird droppings. There are significant opportunities, but
it would take significant investment in the short term for long-term gain.[9]
8.12
The Electrical Trades Union went on to add that many communities in
regional areas are already off‑grid. In addition to existing changes to
how electricity is generated, technological advances such as improved and more
cost-effective battery technology, which could vastly improve the benefits of
solar by enabling the storage of electricity for use at night, have the
potential to further encourage consumers to move off-grid. A representative of
the union stated:
...regardless of whether it is metropolitan or regional...people
are getting more and more solar PV and there are wind farms coming on et
cetera, the generation mix overall is changing quite significantly and there is
a lot more embedded generation at a household level and perhaps, with the
advent of things like battery storage et cetera, that will happen at a
neighbourhood or block level or suburb level. It is absolutely inevitable that
the energy industry is going to change over the next five to 10 years
significantly. It is already happening in studies by scientific organisations
et cetera. We will be really re-evaluating the premise of a centralised
network.[10]
Potential challenges and benefits
for network businesses
8.13
In considering the response to embedded generation, some witnesses argued
there were opportunities for network businesses. For example, Mr Gavin McMahon
from the Central Irrigation Trust suggested that embedded generation could
benefit network businesses by allowing networks to be structured differently
and, if such generation 'had some reasonable paybacks', industries may even
consider co‑investment.[11]
8.14
The committee received evidence that some distributors are considering
changes to their networks; Ergon Energy stated that it is:
...reshaping its business model to create an open access
platform that will enable us to actively coordinate and integrate distributed
energy resources in a way that optimises our existing network assets and
provides dynamic incentives (choice and control) to consumers. Ergon Energy
plans to facilitate two-way flows of energy linking buyers and sellers in a
time and location manner that creates value for customers and Ergon Energy.
Ergon Energy believes this will achieve the best outcome for us and our
customers by providing new revenue opportunities and ultimately reducing
network costs.[12]
8.15
Given that electricity supply is an essential service, it is likely that
the rise of embedded generation will present challenges for the network
businesses. For example, Mr Alistair Parker, a general manager at
AusNet Services, a Victorian distributor, highlighted the implications of the
guaranteed service obligations imposed on network companies:
...if five people in a small community want to go off grid but
one person wants to stay, we still have the obligation to supply that one
person and we still have the obligation to keep that line safe for the most
horrific days.[13]
8.16
Mr Parker added that some consumers are resistant to the idea of moving
off‑grid and relying on embedded generation. Mr Parker noted that
education and increased understanding among consumers of their options may be
needed, but that will take time.[14]
Local energy trading
8.17
Stakeholders highlighted what they considered were flaws in the current
treatment of embedded generation.
8.18
At present, the size of an embedded generator may be limited to meet the
load needed by its owners as the excess energy is of little value. Mr Geoff
Bragg, the New South Wales chairman of the Solar Energy Industries
Association, explained that exported energy is currently 'worth next to
nothing'. He explained that in New South Wales retailers are not obliged to pay
anything for exported energy, and in other states only small amounts were paid.[15]
8.19
To illustrate how the system was not delivering the outcomes embedded
generators wanted, Mr Bragg provided the following example of a PV system on a
commercial property where the energy produced on the weekend when the factory
is closed is effectively gifted to the retailer:
I can think of a 100-kilowatt PV installation we did on a
furniture-manufacturing place. When you consume the energy on-site it is worth
a lot to you—it is worth the full retail value of the energy: not the demand
charges but the energy. However, if you cannot use that energy and you export
it then in New South Wales it is up to the retailer if they pay you anything
for that energy. What that means is that once you get into that small-to
medium-commercial scale, energy retailers will pay nothing.
So all the energy that this factory's 100 kilowatts produces
when it closes on Friday afternoon right through till Monday morning goes to
the retailer for zilch—nothing. They get no credit whatsoever, because no
commercial retailer—Origin, AGL; list them all—would offer them anything for
the energy. It is a windfall for them as the retailers.[16]
8.20
In light of such outcomes, whether local energy trading could be
facilitated was as issue explored in evidence. Mr Bragg concluded that
there was an incentive to move toward a model where local electricity trading
could take place, however, he observed that 'it requires the networks to go
along with it'. Importantly, he explained that charges for the use of the network
would need to be adjusted for a local network:
At the moment there is a distribution use of service [DUOS] charge...on
the basis of the quantity of energy that moves through. That might change or be
broken up into a local use of energy charge—so it is LUOS as opposed to
DUOS—and it will be at a reduced rate. It is about calculating that rate—that
is, the value—of just local energy trading. That is the tricky bit, and there
are some very clever people working on it. It has been done in other countries,
so it is not as if we are breaking new ground. It just has not been done in our
regulatory system. The sooner it happens the sooner you might have a vibrant
distributed energy market where you actually encourage increasing demand rather
than in what is otherwise a very shrinking market. If it is done renewably then
it is not a negative thing. You can say that we have demand here and we can
meet it with clean energy.[17]
8.21
In its submission, the City of Sydney argued that the 'current financial
rewards for local electricity generation projects do not reflect their full
value to electricity consumers or to society as a whole'. Potentially, the City
of Sydney considered that changes to pricing to encourage embedded generation
could result in lower prices for consumers by slowing the growth of expensive
transmission and sub-transmission networks. The City also suggested that this
outcome would reduce the 'tendency for overinvestment in network capacity
upgrades (or for oversized replacement)'.[18]
8.22
The City of Sydney advised that it is working with other interested
parties on a rule change request to introduce a system of reduced charges for
sending electricity from local generators to local customers. The City expects
to lodge this request to the AEMC in May 2015.[19]
Treatment of customers using solar
photovoltaic systems
8.23
The terms of reference for inquiry included consideration of whether the
arrangements for the connection and pricing of network services discriminate
against households and businesses that are involved in their own electricity
production. Submitters that addressed this issue generally focused on solar PV
systems, although divergent views were received on whether the owners were
being discriminated against. Responses addressed the prices and service
received by PV customers; these issues are considered separately in the
following paragraphs.
Price
8.24
The committee received many submissions and letters from consumers with
solar PV systems. One document received by the committee as a submission was a
collection of letters collected by Solar Citizens, which is a community-based
organisation that aims to increase the use of solar power. These letters
expressed concern about the level of, and changes to, feed-in-tariffs compared
to the standard price of electricity. Some consumers who have installed solar
panels also noted they were unsure about their rights in relation to changes in
feed-in-tariffs.[20]
For example, one consumer wrote that they receive:
...eight cents per KW generated yet [are charged] four times
that to use a KW. This is grossly unfair given it is these companies that
failed to update their own infrastructure to cope with the increased use of
solar. We should be on a gross feed in tariff or at best be paid a lot more for
what we generate.[21]
8.25
Another example was provided by Mr Alan Wilson, who wrote:
As a pensioner I looked to
means of reducing my electricity bills and I installed 3 kilowatt solar
panels once the smart metres came to our street.
I am disappointed to find that with the ridiculously low
payment of 8 cents per kilowatt for electricity I generate plus the supply fee
of $1.00 per day makes the repayment of my investment a very lengthy
proposition. As the retailers have to pay a much higher figure to buy power
from the wholesaler/producer, why is the power that I generate worth so much
less?[22]
8.26
Similarly, the City of Sydney noted that private and public buildings
with solar PV systems are paying energy companies disproportionate prices for
importing electricity compared to the price received from energy companies for
exporting electricity. The City considered this is 'a major barrier inhibiting
the uptake of solar PV', and that until this mismatch is addressed, the amount
of installed solar PV 'will be well below what is theoretically possible'.[23]
8.27
However, other stakeholders firmly rejected the presumption that
PV consumers were discriminated against based on price. The ESAA wrote
that the AEMC has confirmed that owners of embedded generators, such as PV
systems, 'are in fact over compensated, receiving a subsidy from other
electricity users'. To illustrate this, the ESAA provided the following
example:
...a household that installs a 2.5kW PV system has its network
costs reduced by around $200 a year, but only provides a saving to other
customers of $80. Other households are left to cover the $120 difference
through higher prices. It should be noted that users with energy intensive
appliances (airconditioners etc.) are also receiving a cross-subsidy.
The subsidy arises as prices are currently largely energy
based (kWh), while network costs are largely due to capacity/maximum demand
(kW). As a PV owner typically reduces their energy consumed without having a
commensurate impact on their maximum demand, it results in their bills reducing
by more than the value of the energy they produce.[24]
8.28
Mr Matthew Warren, the chief executive officer of the ESAA, advised that
he has a solar PV system at his residence. He observed that 'solar households
are often big users of the network':
While we think we do not use much electricity, we are
exporting and importing electricity, and we are quite active users of the
network, so we need to pay our fair share of that network. Then there is the
capacity component. As I said, 30 per cent of network investment is to meet
those summer peaks, and we saw those record levels last year in Victoria and
South Australia. So it is appropriate to charge for capacity usage.[25]
8.29
The Energy Networks Association (ENA) advised that the amount of the
cross‑subsidy solar PV customers receive has been estimated at between
$120 and $163 a year. It added that these cross-subsidies 'are currently far
less than, for instance, the cross-subsidies caused by the use of air conditioning
units at peak times'.[26]
8.30
The New South Wales Irrigators' Council (NSWIC) also did not consider
that PV customers have been discriminated against. The NSWIC argued the large
uptake of solar PV systems demonstrates that the demand for these units was
underestimated and the feed-in-tariffs were too high. The NSWIC similarly noted
the AEMC's analysis of cross-subsidies and suggested that the cost of solar
generated energy being fed into the system is 'only partially paid by those who
have installed solar PV units'. The NSWIC concluded:
These arguments show that a well-intended policy initiative
has created significant distortions in the market and led to unintended cost
implications for third parties.[27]
8.31
The submission from the Department of Industry noted the tension between
the position of embedded generators and other energy consumers. The department
explained that COAG has agreed that:
-
'residential and small business consumers with grid connected
micro generation should have the right to export energy to the electricity
grid'; and
-
payments for exported electricity should reflect 'the value of
that energy to the market and network, taking into account the time of day
during which energy is exported'.[28]
8.32
The department noted that, as indicated by the AEMC analysis, there 'is
a risk that current arrangements may provide a higher return to households and
businesses engaged in self generation than envisaged by these principles'. The
department advised that the AEMC 'is pursuing changes to these pricing rules to
improve the reflection of these network cost signals to consumers considering
grid connected self‑generation'.[29]
Service received by solar PV system
customers
8.33
Another issue is the attitude of network companies to PV systems as
evidenced by the service provided when consumers seek to install these systems.
8.34
The Solar Energy Industries Association explained that customers who
have installed a solar system and need to upgrade and connect the necessary new
meters have found it difficult to deal with distribution network service
providers. Generally, it is claimed that the network business failed to specify
the requirements or process for the meter upgrade and the process was drawn out
over several months.[30]
The Association added that the process of connecting an installed solar
system to the electricity network 'is not clear and seems to change from case
to case'. It concluded that delays of four to five months in connecting an
already installed system 'are difficult to fathom unless the organisation
responsible for approving the connection [the distribution network service
provider]...is against a solar system being installed'.[31]
8.35
Ms Claire O'Rourke, the national director of Solar Citizens, noted the
letters Solar Citizens compiled for the committee contained a number of common
themes about mistakes made by energy businesses that financially disadvantaged
customers with solar panels. These errors included:
-
'unfair or hidden charges' that the customer was not aware of at
the time of installation;
-
an increase in service charges following the installation of a
solar PV system; and
-
high quotes for the installation of poles and wires in rural
areas.[32]
8.36
Mr Geoff Bragg from the Solar Energy Industries Association acknowledged
that there are technical issues with the connection of PV to the grid, and that
often upgraded infrastructure is required. However, he emphasised that the cost
of this upgraded infrastructure is imposed on the proponent of the PV project.
Mr Bragg contrasted this with the attitude of network businesses when
faced with the need to upgrade infrastructure when a customer wants to use more
energy, rather than generate their own. Mr Bragg provided the following
example:
I can think of a residential customer recently who would like
to put a large PV system on, but their supply transformer in a rural location
is not big enough. If they want to put in a bigger transformer they will have
to pay for that, at considerable cost—$20,000 or $30,000—which would write off
the viability of the PV project. However, if they go to the distribution
network and say, 'I'd like to put two more air-conditioners on the other side
of my house they will come out, at a very subsidised cost, and put in a bigger
transformer to supply.' This is the way that it works in reality on the ground.[33]
Recent changes and future options
8.37
The submissions from the AEMC and the Department of Industry highlighted
changes intended to improve the standing of customers involved in embedded
generation.
8.38
The department's submission considered the issue of potential
discrimination that embedded generation customers may face. The department
highlighted the COAG Energy Council's National Energy Customer Framework (NECF)
that commenced progressively in certain states from July 2012. The department
stated that under the NECF, 'residential and small business energy customers
are supported by a range of robust customer protections'. These protections
include measures that govern the interactions retailers and distributors have
with customers, such as minimum terms and conditions for retail and connection
contracts'.[34]
8.39
The AEMC noted that two rule changes made in 2014 'established a new
framework for the efficient connection of embedded generators to distribution
networks'. The AEMC provided the following explanation of what the new rules
seek to achieve:
The new rules provide a clearer, more transparent connection
process with defined timeframes, and require distributors to publish
information to assist embedded generators. They also provide embedded generator
proponents with more choices about how to connect. The rules aim to reduce
barriers that embedded generator proponents have faced in attempting to connect
to distribution networks. Removal of such barriers is in the long-term interest
of consumers who benefit from efficient investment in embedded generation via
reduced network requirements.[35]
8.40
While the AEMC's rule changes received some support, the City of Sydney
argued that several issues remained unresolved. The City argued:
-
the option of applying as a wholesale connection will not benefit
most small‑scale connection applicants;
-
there 'remains a very marked asymmetry of power in the
relationship between connection applicants and electricity networks'; and
-
the reasonableness of connection costs has not been addressed.[36]
8.41
The City of Sydney considered that connection package offers from distribution
network businesses should be standardised to cover major classes of embedded
generation, such as reciprocating gas engines and solar installations.
The City added that under these packages:
The cost of distributors 'learning
on the job' or bringing network practices up to scratch should be borne by (or
at least shared with) distribution networks. If necessary, distribution networks
should allocate additional resources to the process and allow for this in the
costs of operation for which they seek approval from AER.[37]
8.42
The City of Sydney also considered that the costs imposed on applicants
should be limited so that they did not exceed 'the costs that would be incurred
by a network that was appropriately designed and reasonably equipped to meet
current and emerging network challenges'. Finally, the City added that
additional resolution mechanisms for connection applications are needed.[38]
Demand management
8.43
An effective demand-side response to pressures on the network can be
provided if consumers are provided with incentives to reduce their consumptions
during critical peak periods. Demand management refers to arrangements that
allow consumers to commit to doing this and where the customers are compensated
for doing so. The Public Interest Advocacy Centre explained that critical
peak demand events generally occur 'on hot days, when household air conditioner
use is at its highest'. If demand management can reduce demand, potentially
peak demand could be significantly reduced. It follows that, over time, increases
in overall network costs for consumers should be lower as 'network capacity to
meet peak demand is the key driver of network expenditure'.[39]
8.44
The Queensland Consumers' Association explained that it has advocated
for many years, largely unsuccessfully, for demand management measures to be a
high priority. The Association particularly focused on direct load control.[40]
It argued that there are 'large potential benefits...from voluntary direct load
control of household air conditioners', however, failure to adequately
respond to this has resulted in higher electricity prices. It explained that
the need for voluntary direct load control of household air conditioners:
...became apparent several years ago when the use of air
conditioners began to expand very rapidly. Yet industry and governments failed
to quickly develop and implement policies to overcome impediments to the use of
direct load control of air conditioners. The Association considers that this
was a major public policy failure.
The failure nationally to use direct load control
sufficiently to address the problem has resulted in a massive increase in peak
demand in many states, especially late in the afternoon on very hot days, and
in the network augmentation and replacement investments needed to meet it.
These investments have in turn substantially pushed up power prices to
consumers.[41]
8.45
The Total Environment Centre noted that demand management is 'an obvious
way to constrain retail prices in the future', given network building to 'meet
projected (though often not actual) increases in peak demand' has been one of
the major drivers of higher electricity prices. However, the Total Environment Centre
argued that demand management has been 'poorly utilised by networks in
Australia'.[42]
The Centre concluded that the poor uptake of demand management is due to:
-
a lack of incentives in the National Electricity Rules (NER) for
network businesses to undertake demand management as a profitable alternative
to capital expenditure; and
-
the Australian Energy Regulator (AER) not exercising its discretion
to encourage network businesses to give a greater focus to demand management in
their regulatory proposals.[43]
8.46
The ENA noted that network businesses have been undertaking demand
management activities 'in the context of the network responsibilities to find
the most cost effective and efficient solutions to address demand growth within
the context of network investment'. The ENA explained that, for network
augmentation to be offset by demand management, network security considerations
require 'that the loads controlled are reliably removed from peak periods'. Despite
this challenge, peak demand has been reduced by demand management 'through
initiatives such as managing peak hot water systems, rebates for efficient air
conditioners, direct load control of major appliances and pricing agreements
with large customers'.[44]
8.47
Demand management was considered by the AEMC in its 2012 'power of
choice' review. That review 'was focused on improving consumer engagement in
the market and facilitating more active consumer participation'.[45]
The Power of choice report noted that the NER allow the AER to develop
and apply a separate incentive scheme for demand management, referred to as the
demand management and embedded generation connection incentive scheme (DMEGCIS).
However, the AEMC concluded that a more comprehensive demand management
incentive scheme needs to be applied to distribution network businesses. The Power
of choice report recommended that amendments to the NER be developed to:
...reform the application of the current demand management and
embedded generation connection incentive scheme so that it:
- provides an appropriate return for
[demand side participation] projects that deliver a net cost saving to
consumers; and
-
better aligns network incentives
with the objective of achieving efficient demand management.
This would include creating separate provisions for an
innovation allowance.[46]
8.48
The AEMC drafted a rule change that would add more principles and
criteria to the DMEGCIS.[47]
Public consultation on a rule change request related to the DMEGCIS commenced
in February 2015.[48]
8.49
The ENA and specific network businesses, such as Ergon Energy, expressed
their support for a review of demand management, as recommended by the AEMC.[49]
However, some stakeholders expressed frustration at the delay in action being
taken on demand management via the AEMC process. For example, Dr Gabrielle
Kuiper from the Public Interest Advocacy Centre suggested that the AEMC was
'not performing its functions in a timely manner'. Dr Kuiper added that her
organisation was disappointed the AER's recent draft determinations stated that
the AER would not be proposing a new demand management incentive scheme until
the AEMC process on demand management is completed.[50]
The Total Environment Centre similarly noted that the AER has been unwilling to
introduce an effective incentive scheme pending the AEMC's decision on a rule
change.[51]
8.50
When asked why the AER is not going to set demand management performance
targets for distribution network businesses, an AER officer confirmed that 'at
least one of the New South Wales businesses wanted us to apply a stronger
incentive regime for demand-side management'. However, the AER's position is
that within 'the policy framework, those issues are still, at a broader level,
being looked at'. The officer provided the following explanation:
We felt that it would be rather pre-emptive of us to support
specific types of those things before the rule framework had been amended. I
think the AEMC is just about to begin its processes to change the rules and to
allow other types of incentive schemes to apply in this area. We agree with
those things, however we felt that the rule framework needs to be enhanced
first.[52]
Network tariff reform
8.51
Tariff structures can influence consumers to consider their energy usage
and to become involved in embedded generation, change their consumption
patterns or undertake energy efficiency measures. This section considers the
evidence received on moves toward higher fixed network charges before
considering more general calls for network tariff reform.
Fixed charges
8.52
The committee received complaints about certain existing network
tariffs. Changes to fixed or service charges was a common grievance,
particularly for customers who had installed their own embedded generation such
as a solar PV system. The Total Environment Centre argued that moves to
increase fixed daily charges reflected the vested interest network businesses
have in 'maintaining their status as protected monopolies, rather than being
open to competition from new technologies and services'. The Centre argued that
increases in fixed daily charges were occurring in the face of declining
consumption and in an attempt to restrict competition from PV systems.[53]
8.53
The rationale for increased fixed charges was provided by Mr Ian McLeod,
the chief executive of Ergon Energy. Mr McLeod argued that tariffs structures
have historically been largely based on volume, whereas the network 'is
generally a fixed cost'. While expounding this argument, Mr McLeod compared
household electricity costs to other regular costs a household faces:
It is like having your house. You go on holidays and you
still have to pay for your loan, you still have to pay for the connections to
it and all those sorts of things.[54]
8.54
Increased fixed charges are also affecting agricultural businesses. Like
other organisations representing energy users, the Agriculture Industries
Electricity Taskforce expressed suspicion that higher fixed charges were
intended to make it more difficult for people to reduce their electricity bills
by reducing the amount of electricity they consume from the grid. However, the
Taskforce also directly countered the argument that fixed costs should be
recovered by fixed charges:
We believe they have confused sunk (historic) costs with
(current) fixed charges. There is no basis in the theory of electricity pricing
for sunk costs to be recovered through fixed charges.[55]
Demand-based tariffs
8.55
Changes to demand-based tariffs for large businesses were also criticised,
particularly by agricultural businesses. The Agriculture Industries Electricity
Taskforce stated that demand charges are a 'major concern' for its members. It explained
that there is:
...little that our members can do to reduce demand charges by
moving their peak demands to times that are likely to be more advantageous to
the system and hence beneficial for other energy consumers as well. This is
completely contrary to the insistence of the networks that they are pursing 'cost
reflective' tariffs.[56]
8.56
Mr Michael Murray from Cotton Australia explained that 'irrigators who
rely on electricity to harvest in accordance with their licence conditions are
particularly penalised by the move to demand-based tariffs'. He continued:
In New South Wales, many of our growers are already on these
grossly inappropriate tariffs, while in Queensland a transition process is
underway which will force many onto demand tariffs by 2020. We modelled the
impact on irrigators in the St George district of Queensland, and demand‑based
tariffs for water harvesters will typically increase bills by 200 to 300 per
cent. In one example, an irrigator currently on tariff 62 with a bill of around
$150,000 a year would have been slugged with a bill of $450,000 for that same
year while using exactly the same number of kilowatts of electricity—that is,
with no change in usage—just in the way that the tariff is structured. Clearly
our fibre producers cannot absorb such dramatic increases in costs. There
desperately needs to be a reform in how network revenues and tariffs are
determined.[57]
8.57
In the absence of change, Mr Murray suggested that an irrigator facing
an increase in an electricity bill from $150,000 to $450,000 is likely to
'simply replace his electric motors with diesel ones'.[58]
8.58
The committee also heard that sugar mills in Queensland will be required
to change to a new tariff over the next five years. It is expected that this
tariff will result in tariffs for those businesses that are 40 per cent higher
than the current tariffs. Ms Sharon Denny from the Australian Sugar
Milling Council explained:
Currently, most of our members are on tariff 22. That tariff
is being phased out over the next five years and they will be moved to tariff
48. Now, that tariff 48 has a range of additional charges inside it that our
mills do not see under tariff 22, although we anticipate that some of those
charges will start to flow through into tariff 22 as well. At today's prices,
with QCA price determination, the difference between tariff 22 and tariff 48
for our mills would be a 40 per cent price increase; but in five years' time,
obviously, that price increase will be higher again. That is just the best
comparison we can do today with what we know of published figures.[59]
8.59
Mr Warren Males of Canegrowers added that although some of these tariffs
have been described as 'obsolete', they were only obsolete because the
distributor has decided they do not support the continued existence of
particular tariffs. Mr Males advised that efforts to engage with the
distributor about a tariff appropriate for food and fibre production have been
undertaken, however, the distributor (which in this case is Ergon) has not been
receptive.[60]
General calls for network tariff
reform
8.60
There appeared to be general agreement that network tariff reform was
desirable. The perspective of policymakers was provided by the Department of
Industry, which argued that network tariff reform 'is crucial to drive
behaviours that minimise network costs and support more efficient network utilisation'.
The department noted that industry are driving reforms in this area,
however, it suggested that governments can:
-
encourage industry to take action on opportunities provided by
new rules;
-
support efforts to improve customer understanding of tariff
reform; and
-
ensure that appropriate consumer protections support vulnerable
consumers.[61]
8.61
The Energy Users Association of Australia (EUAA) argued that current
approaches to network pricing are 'not cost reflective'. In particular, the
EUAA claimed that the current pricing methodologies used by networks 'lack
transparency, produce highly variable outcomes for consumers, and do not
reflect the increasing diversity in how consumers use energy'.[62]
8.62
Electricity networks and their industry associations also desired
network tariff reform. The ENA called for a 'comprehensive reform program for
electricity distribution network tariffs and enabling metering'. The ENA
explained that use of the networks varies due to 'increasingly diverse load
profiles', depending on the use of air conditioning, energy efficient
devices and practices, solar panels and other technologies. Despite this:
...most Australian electricity distribution network tariffs
rely on volumetric charges (cents per kilowatt hour) which do not vary by time.
They bear little relation to drivers of network cost, resulting in unfair
cross-subsidies between customers today and a failure to signal the costs of
increased network investment which would be required in the future.[63]
8.63
The ENA envisaged that network tariff reform would result in customers
paying tariffs that 'are more cost‑reflective rather than paying a flat
or "average" rate based on their electricity usage'. These tariffs
would enable customers to make better informed decisions about their use of
electricity network services and whether to invest in technology to help manage
their consumption.[64]
The ESAA noted tariffs that contained a 'capacity/demand' element will ensure
that customers with embedded generation 'are appropriately paid for the
services they provide' and that customers who 'impose significant costs on the
grid pay for these costs'.[65]
8.64
A submission from the president of the Hastings Branch of Climate Change
Australia, Mr Harry Creamer, called for a shift from flat-rate tariffs to
time-of-use tariffs. Mr Creamer noted this would enable households to be
charged according to loads they impose on the network, although it would
require a national roll-out of smart meters.[66]
However, Mr Creamer added:
...it would be extremely unfair to charge consumers based on
the single highest demand figure recorded per day, as some retailers are
suggesting. Governments, businesses and regulators must be clear that the total
amount of revenue will not change.[67]
8.65
The City of Sydney supported network tariff reform that better reflects
the contribution made by embedded generators. The City submitted that the
setting of network tariffs and charges should 'take into account the relative
use of system resources in an efficiently designed and managed system'. The
City argued that 'using less system resources to supply energy to customers
should be rewarded with a lower overall tariff'.[68]
8.66
While many submitters expressed support for some type of tariff reform,
at least one group had reservations given the nebulous nature of the concept. Based
on the recent experiences of its members with changing tariffs, the Agriculture
Industries Electricity Taskforce expressed concern that network companies may
be calling for tariff reform as part of an effort to maintain their dominant
position in the electricity market. The Taskforce stated:
We understand that the AEMC intends to make changes to the
National Electricity Rules to mandate that tariffs should be 'cost reflective'.
We do not know what this will mean in practice, but we are concerned that
networks will use 'tariff reform' as an opportunity to undermine the prospects
for energy efficiency and distributed generation, both of which are competitive
threats to their business.[69]
8.67
The Consumer Action Law Centre noted that the AEMC has recently worked
on network tariff arrangements with the view to reducing existing
cross-subsidies, so that 'those that create a burden on the system (i.e. those
with high air conditioner use)...pay for that burden'. Under the changes, network
tariffs must be based on long‑run marginal cost. Network businesses must
also consider the impact of changes on consumers and must develop price
structures that consumers can understand. However, the Centre noted that the
AEMC's decision on this issue limited the role of the AER in relation to
network tariffs and left 'significant discretion to the network businesses'.
The Centre pointed out that 'while each network tariff must be based on long‑run
marginal cost, network businesses will have flexibility about how they measure
long run marginal cost'.[70]
8.68
Although the Total Environment Centre is of the view that high fixed
daily charges are inconsistent with the principle of long-run marginal cost, it
warned that the rule change will not prevent network companies from seeking to
maintain their revenue by increasing fixed charges.[71]
8.69
Finally, the EUAA noted that the benefits of more efficient
cost-reflective pricing through tariff reform were dependant on other issues
with electricity regulation being addressed. Mr Mark Grenning, a member of the
EUAA board, explained that if the inefficient investment included in the asset
base is not addressed, then regardless of the tariffs in place consumers will
still be required to pay high prices because of past gold-plating and stranded
assets.[72]
Committee view
8.70
Australia has a large and expensive electricity network built as a
result of decades of centralised generation. The evidence taken during this
inquiry revealed that stakeholders are increasingly starting to consider
whether the current system of networks, and the regulations governing it, can
be sustained. In the coming years, this network arrangement may no longer effectively
deal with how a significant amount of electricity is generated and distributed.
Sustained high network costs and improvements in technology, such as advances
in battery storage, may result in a market that demands a smaller, more local,
network rather than the expansive networks based on centralised generation.
8.71
The committee considers that, given the concern that electricity
networks are entering a 'death spiral', policymakers and regulators need to
closely monitor developments in the electricity market to ensure network
businesses do not discriminate against customers who seek to engage in embedded
generation. It is also important that the customers who continue to be supplied
with electricity in the conventional manner, particularly customers who cannot
afford to invest in their own electricity generation system, are not forced to
pay an increasing share of network costs as a result of other customers going
'off-grid'.
8.72
Given the likely changes in the energy market, the committee considers
it is important that the regulatory framework is flexible so it can respond
quickly in a way that ensures networks operate in the long-term interests of
consumers. Identifying and removing impediments to change must be a priority of
energy policymakers and regulators. Developments in the market, particularly
due to 'behind-the-meter' electricity generated by customers, need to be acted
on in a timely manner once anticipated or identified.
Recommendation 15
8.73
The committee recommends that the Australian, state and territory
governments increase and prioritise efforts to ensure that networks are
prepared to efficiently respond to changes in the energy market, in light of:
-
the increased uptake of small-scale solar generation;
-
emerging energy storage technologies;
-
the anticipation of customers going 'off-grid';
-
the anticipation of further disruptive technologies; and
-
the certainty of value destruction as a result of current
business models.
Recommendation 16
8.74
The committee recommends that, as cost-reflective network pricing is
introduced, the COAG Energy Council ensure appropriate steps are taken so
network companies' tariff and non-tariff based demand management programs are
strengthened to assist consumers to transition to cost-reflective tariffs.
Recommendation 17
8.75
The committee recommends that the Australian Energy Regulator expedite
its implementation of the current demand management incentive scheme rule
change in all open network revenue determinations.
Recommendation 18
8.76
The committee recommends that the COAG Energy Council remove any barriers
to networks implementing cost-reflective network prices to ensure efficient use
of demand management and embedded generation is rewarded.
Senator
Anne Urquhart
Chair
Navigation: Previous Page | Contents | Next Page